How Game Theory Strategy Improves Decision-Making (2024)

Game theory, the study of strategic decision-making, brings together elements of mathematics, psychology, and philosophy. In Neumann and Oskar Morgenstern in 1944, it has come a long way since then.

Its importance to modern analysis and decision-making can be gauged by the fact that as many as 12 leading economists and scientists have been awarded the Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences for their contributions to game theory since 1970.

Game theory is applied in fields including business, finance, economics, political science, and psychology. Understanding its strategies—both the popular ones and some of the relatively lesser-known—is important to enhance one’s reasoning and decision-making skills in a complex world.

Key Takeaways

  • Game theory is a framework for understanding choice in situationsthat involve competing players.
  • A common game form in economic and business situations is the prisoner's dilemma, in which individual decision-makers have the incentive to choose a path that produces a less-than-optimal outcome for the individuals as a group.
  • The practical application of games can be useful in any strategic interaction between two or more actors.

Prisoner’s Dilemma

One of the most popular and basic game theory strategies is the prisoner's dilemma, a role-playing game.

Two suspects apprehended for a crime are held in separate rooms and cannot communicate with each other. The prosecutor informs both Suspect 1 and Suspect 2 individually that if heconfesses and testifies against the other he can go free, but if he does not cooperate and the other suspect does, hewill be sentenced to three years in prison. If both confess, they will get a two-year sentence, and if neither confesses, they will be sentenced to one year in prison.

Cooperation is the best strategy for the two suspects when confronted with such a dilemma. However, research shows that most rational people prefer to confess and testify against the other person rather than stay silent and take the chance the other party confesses.

This explores the decision-making strategy taken by two individuals who, by acting in their own individual best interest, end up with worse outcomes than if they had cooperated.

The prisoner's dilemma lays the foundation for advanced game theory strategies. Below are some of the most popular ones.

It is assumed players within the game are rational and will strive to maximize their payoffs in the game.

Matching Pennies

Matching pennies is a zero-sum game. One player's gain is always the other player's loss.

It involves two players (call them Player A and Player B) simultaneously placing a penny on the table, with the payoff depending on whether the pennies match. If both pennies are heads or tails, Player A wins and keeps Player B’s penny. If they do not match, Player B wins and keeps Player A’s penny.

Deadlock

This is a social dilemma scenario in that two players can either cooperate or defect.

In a deadlock, if Player A and Player B both cooperate, they each get a payoff of 1, and if they both defect, they each get a payoff of 2.

But if Player A cooperates and Player B defects, then A gets a payoff of 0 and B gets a payoff of 3. In the payoff diagram below, the first numeral in the cells (a) through (d) represents Player A’s payoff, and the second numeral is that of Player B:

Deadlock Payoff MatrixPlayer BPlayer B
CooperateDefect
Player ACooperate(a) 1, 1(b) 0, 3
Defect(c) 3, 0(d) 2, 2

Deadlock differs from prisoner’s dilemma in that the action of greatest mutual benefit (i.e. both defect) is also the dominant strategy. A dominant strategy for a player is defined as one that produces the highest payoff of any available strategy, regardless of the strategies employed by the other players.

A commonly cited example of deadlock is that of two nuclear powers trying to reach an agreement to eliminate their arsenals of nuclear bombs. In this case, cooperation implies adhering to the agreement, while defection means secretly reneging on the agreement and retaining the nuclear arsenal.

The best outcome for either nation, unfortunately, is to renege on the agreement and retain the nuclear option while the other nation eliminates its arsenal since this will give the former a tremendous hidden advantage over the latter if war ever breaks out between the two.

The second-best option is for both to defect or not cooperate since this retains their status as nuclear powers.

Cournot Competition

This model is also conceptually similar to the prisoner’s dilemma and is named after French mathematician Augustin Cournot, who introduced it in 1838. The most common application of the Cournot model is to describe a duopoly or two main producers in a market.

For example, assume companies A and B produce an identical product and can produce high or low quantities. If they cooperate and agree to produce at low levels, then limited supply will translate into a high price for the product on the market and substantial profits for both companies. If they defect and produce at high levels, the market will be swamped and result in a low price for the product and lower profits for both. But if one cooperates (i.e. produces at low levels) and the other defects (i.e. surreptitiously produces at high levels), then the former just breaks even while the latter earns a higherprofitthan if they both cooperate.

The payoff matrix for companies A and B is shown (figures represent profit in millions of dollars). Thus, if A cooperates and produces at low levels while B defects and produces at high levels, the payoff is as shown in the cell (b)—break-even for company A and $7 million in profits for company B.

Cournot Payoff MatrixCompany BCompany B
CooperateDefect
Company ACooperate(a) 4, 4(b) 0, 7
Defect(c) 7, 0(d) 2, 2

Coordination Game

In the coordination game, players earn higher payoffs when they select the same course of action.

As an example, consider two technology giants who are deciding between introducing a radical new technology in memory chips that could earn them hundreds of millions in profits, or a revised version of an older technology that would earn them much less. If only one company decides to go ahead with the new technology, rate ofadoption by consumers would be significantly lower, and as a result, it would earn less than if both companies decide on the same course of action. The payoff matrix is shown below (figures represent profit in millions of dollars).

Thus, if both companies decide to introduce the new technology, they would earn $600 million apiece, while introducing a revised version of the older technology would earn them $300 million each, as shown in cell (d). But if Company A decides alone to introduce the new technology, it would only earn $150 million, even though Company B would earn $0 (presumably because consumers may not be willing to pay for its now obsolete technology). In this case, it makes sense for both companies to work together rather than on their own.

Coordination Playoff MatrixCompany BCompany B
New TechnologyOld Technology
Company ANew Technology(a) 600, 600(b) 0, 150
Old Technology(c) 150, 0(d) 300, 300

Centipede Game

This is an extensive-form game in which two players alternately get a chance to take the larger share of a slowly increasing money stash. The centipede game is sequential since the players make their moves one after another rather than simultaneously; each player also knows the strategies chosen by the players who played before them. The game concludes as soon as a player takes the stash, with that player getting the larger portion and the other player getting the smaller portion.

As an example,assume Player A goes first and has to decide if he should “take” or “pass” the stash, which currently amounts to $2. If he takes, then A and B get $1 each, but if A passes, the decision to take or passnow has to be made by Player B. If B takes, she gets $3 (i.e. the previous stash of $2 + $1) and A gets $0. But if B passes, A now gets to decide whether to take or pass, and so on. If both players always choose to pass, they each receive a payoff of $100 at the end of the game.

The point of the game is if A and B both cooperate and continue topassuntilthe end of the game, they get the maximum payoutof $100 each. But if they distrust the other player and expect them to “take” at the first opportunity,Nash equilibrium predicts theplayers will take the lowest possible claim ($1 in this case). Experimental studies have shown, however, this “rational” behavior (as predicted by game theory) is seldom exhibited in real life. This is not intuitively surprising given the tiny size of the initial payoutin relation to the final one. Similar behavior by experimental subjects has also been exhibited in the traveler’s dilemma.

Traveler’s Dilemma

Thisnon-zero-sum game, in which both players attempt to maximize their own payoutwithout regard to the other, was devised by economist Kaushik Basu in 1994.

For example, an airline agrees to pay two travelers compensation for damages to identical items. However, the two travelers are separately required to estimate the value of the item, with a minimum of $2 and a maximum of $100. If both write down the same value, the airline will reimburse each of them that amount. But if the values differ, the airline will pay them the lower value, with a bonus of $2 for the traveler who wrote down this lower value and a penalty of $2 for the traveler who wrote down the higher value.

The Nash equilibrium level, based on backward induction, is $2 in this scenario. But as in the centipede game, laboratory experiments consistently demonstrate most participants,naively or otherwise,pick a number much higher than $2.

Traveler’s dilemma can be applied to analyze a variety of real-life situations. The process of backward induction, for example, can help explain how two companies engaged in cutthroat competition can steadily ratchet product prices lower in a bid to gain market share. This may result in both incurring increasingly greater losses.

Battle of the Sexes

This is another form of the coordination game described earlier, but with some payoffasymmetries. It essentially involves a couple trying to coordinate their evening out.

While they had agreed to meet at either the ball game (the man’s preference) or at a play (the woman’s preference), they have forgotten what they decided, and to compound, the problem, cannot communicate with one another. Where should they go?

The payoff matrix isshown below withthe numerals in the cells representing the relative degree of enjoyment of the event for the woman and man, respectively. For example, cell (a) represents the payoff (in terms of enjoyment levels) for the woman and manat the play (she enjoys it much more than he does). Cell (d) is the payoff if both make it to the ball game (he enjoys it more than she does). Cell (c) represents the dissatisfaction if both go not only to the wrong location but also to the event they enjoy least—the woman to the ball game and the man to the play.

Battle of the Sexes Payoff MatrixManMan
PlayBall Game
WomanPlay(a) 6, 3(b) 2, 2
Ball Game(c) 0, 0(d) 3, 6

Dictator Game

This is a simple game in which Player A must decide how to split a cash prize with Player B, who has no input into Player A’s decision.

While this is not a game theory strategy per se, it does provide some interesting insights into people’s behavior. Experiments reveal about 50% keep all the money to themselves,5% split it equallyand the other 45% give the other participant a smaller share.

The dictator game is closely related to the ultimatum game, in which Player A is given a set amount of money, part of which has to be given to Player B, who can accept or reject the amount given. The catch isif the second player rejects the amount offered, both A and B get nothing. The dictator and ultimatum games hold important lessons for issues such as charitable giving and philanthropy.

Peace-War

This is a variation of the prisoner’s dilemma in which the “cooperate or defect” decisions are replaced by “peace or war.”

An analogy could be two companies engaged in a price war. If both refrain from price cutting, they enjoy relative prosperity (cell a), but aprice war would reduce payoffs dramatically (cell d). However, if A engages in price-cutting (i.e., "war") but B does not, A would have a higher payoff of 4 since it may be able to capture substantial market share, and this higher volume would offset lower product prices.

Peace-War Payoff MatrixCompany BCompany B
PeaceWar
Company APeace(a) 3, 3(b) 0, 4
War(c) 4, 0(d) 1, 1

Volunteer’s Dilemma

In a volunteer’s dilemma, someone has to undertake a chore or job for the common good. The worst possible outcome is realized if nobody volunteers.

For example, consider a company where accounting fraud is rampant but top management is unaware of it. Some junior employees in the accounting department are aware of the fraud but hesitate to tell top managementbecause it would result in the employees involved in the fraud being fired and most likely prosecuted.

Being labeled as a whistleblowermay also have some repercussions down the line. But if nobody volunteers, the large-scale fraud may result in the company’s eventual bankruptcy and the loss of everyone’s jobs.

What Are the Games Being Played in Game Theory?

They are multiplayer role-playing games. Each player must decide on a course of action while taking into account the potential actions of the other players.

It is called game theory since its objective is to understand the strategic decision-making processes of two or more players in a given situation containing definite rules and known outcomes.

What Does the Prisoner's Dilemma Teach Us?

The prisoner’s dilemma shows that cooperation is not always in an individual's best interests.

In the real world, when shopping for a big-ticket item such as a car, bargaining is the preferred course of action from the consumers' point of view. Otherwise, the car dealership may adopt a policy of inflexibility in price negotiations, maximizing its profits but resulting in consumers overpaying for their vehicles.

Understanding the relative payoffs of cooperating versus defecting may stimulate you to engage in significantprice negotiationsbefore you make a big purchase.

What Is a Nash Equilibrium in Game Theory?

Nash equilibrium in game theory is a static situation in which each individual has no incentive to deviate from an initial strategy. It is named after the mathematician John Nash.

How Can Businesses Use Game Theory As They Compete With One Another?

Cournot competition, for example, is an economic model describing an industry structure in which rival companies offering an identical product compete on the amount of output they produce, independently and at the same time. It is effectively a prisoner's dilemma game.

The Bottom Line

Game theory is a type of role-playing that can be used to develop an understanding of one's own motivations, and those of others. More importantly, it can help fine-tune a person's skills at negotiating for mutually beneficial results. Such skills are useful whether in an adversarial, business, or personal setting.

Article Sources

Investopedia requires writers to use primary sources to support their work. These include white papers, government data, original reporting, and interviews with industry experts. We also reference original research from other reputable publishers where appropriate. You can learn more about the standards we follow in producing accurate, unbiased content in oureditorial policy.

Related Articles
The Prisoner’s Dilemma in Business and the Economy Game Theory What Does Tit for Tat Mean, and How Does It Work? What Is Backward Induction? Definition, How It Works, and Example Traveler's Dilemma: What It is, How It Works Comparing a Dominant Strategy Solution vs. Nash Equilibrium Solution

Partner Links

Related Terms

Game Theory

Game theory is a framework for modeling scenarios in which conflicts of interest exist among the players.

more

What Does Tit for Tat Mean, and How Does It Work?

Tit for tat is a game theory strategy in which a player chooses the action that the opposing player chose in the previous round of play.

more

What Is Backward Induction? Definition, How It Works, and Example

In game theory, backward induction is the process of deducing backward from the end of a problem or scenario to infer a sequence of optimal actions. See how it works.

more

Traveler's Dilemma: What It is, How It Works

The traveler's dilemma demonstrates the paradox of rationality—that making decisions illogically often produces a better payoff in game theory.

more

Centipede Game: What it Means, How it Works

The centipede game in game theory involves two players alternately getting a chance to take the larger share of an increasing money stash.

more

Zero-Sum Game Definition in Finance, With Example

A zero-sum game is a situation in which one person’s gain is equivalent to another’s loss, so that the net change in wealth or benefit is zero.

more

  • #
  • A
  • B
  • C
  • D
  • E
  • F
  • G
  • H
  • I
  • J
  • K
  • L
  • M
  • N
  • O
  • P
  • Q
  • R
  • S
  • T
  • U
  • V
  • W
  • X
  • Y
  • Z

Investopedia is part of the Dotdash Meredithpublishingfamily.

Please review our updatedTerms of Service.

How Game Theory Strategy Improves Decision-Making (2024)
Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Duncan Muller

Last Updated:

Views: 5546

Rating: 4.9 / 5 (79 voted)

Reviews: 86% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Duncan Muller

Birthday: 1997-01-13

Address: Apt. 505 914 Phillip Crossroad, O'Konborough, NV 62411

Phone: +8555305800947

Job: Construction Agent

Hobby: Shopping, Table tennis, Snowboarding, Rafting, Motor sports, Homebrewing, Taxidermy

Introduction: My name is Duncan Muller, I am a enchanting, good, gentle, modern, tasty, nice, elegant person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.